Boao Review: The Realities of Renminbi Internationalization
I have an article in the October 2012 issue of Boao Review, the new journal published by the Boao Forum, on what the future may hold for China’s currency, the Renminbi. I am told the article will be posted on the magazine’s website this week, and I will post a link when one is available.
The Rise of the Renminbi as an International Currency: Challenges and Solutions
By Patrick Chovanec
The rise of the Renminbi as an international currency is looked up with an almost breathless anticipation from London to Tokyo to Sydney. All this excitement has tended to eclipse a more sober assessment of the opportunities and obstacles the Chinese yuan realistically faces, as well as the benefits and burdens a larger international role for the Renminbi would pose for China. Rarely are the questions asked: Does China really want or need to manage a global currency? And if so, what price is it willing to pay?
The growing role of the Renminbi in China
The Renminbi has already come a long way. Not that long ago, the Renminbi wasn’t a fully functional currency even within China’s own borders. All imported goods, as well as services provided to foreign visitors, had to be paid for with Foreign Exchange Certificates (FEC), in exchange for hard currencies. While FEC were ostensibly denominated in the same yuan as the Renminbi used for domestic purposes, their buying power was obviously quite different, giving rise to a vibrant black market on the doorstep of every international hotel across the country.
Gradually, the yuan’s exchange rate was allowed to depreciate nearly sixfold, from 1.5 CNY/USD to 8.2, closing the trading gap and allowing China to phase out the FEC in 1995. This opened the door for China to make the Renminbi convertible for current account (i.e., trade) transactions the following year. The flow of investment funds both into and out of China via the capital account, however, continued to be strictly regulated. When China set up its two domestic stock exchanges in the early 1990s, it went so far as to create an entirely separate market in so-called “B shares,” denominated in US dollars and HK dollars respectively, in which foreigners (and until 2001, only foreigners) were allowed to invest. In effect, the inability to freely buy and sell Renminbi was used as a firewall to insulate China’s financial markets from the outside world.
In practice, convertibility on the current account meant that Chinese companies, or foreign companies operating in China, could exchange Renminbi for foreign currencies to purchase imports, as long as they presented a valid invoice. Trade itself, both imports and exports, was conducted almost entirely in foreign currencies, mainly in US dollars.
The role of the US dollar in international settlement and its effect on international trade
It’s worth pausing for a moment and asking, why US dollars? After the US de-linked the dollar from gold in 1971, demolishing the post-war Bretton Woods system, there has been no institutional framework enshrining the US dollar as the world’s preeminent currency. The dollar retains its role because market participants prefer to use it, for three main reasons:
- The dollar represents a claim on goods and services in the world’s largest economy, presuming it retains its value;
- The dollar can be freely used or exchanged for any (legal) purpose, without restriction;
- The dollar can be held in a wide range of readily traded investment instruments, and in large amounts.
The same is true of other international currencies, such as the Euro, the British pound, and the Japanese Yen, but to a lesser degree. In contrast, someone who accepts a Chinese yuan as payment – or a Nigerian naira, a Honduran lempira, or a Laotian kip – may find it a lot harder to invest or find another trader who will accept it in turn. Many of these countries find it easier – or even essential – to conduct trade in a currency that is far more widely accepted.
Using the dollar as an intermediary, however, does have costs. Take, for instance, an Argentinian exporter selling soybeans to China. Since the seller can’t use yuan, and the buyer doesn’t want pesos, they both must pay a bank commission to change their money into dollars and then back again. They may have no choice but to use a U.S. bank that has sufficient dollars available. Thus both sides run the risk that their currencies will fluctuate in value against the US dollar before the transaction is completed, creating undesired gains and losses.
The drawbacks of relying on the US dollar were driven home by the immediate aftermath of the Lehman Brothers collapse in September 2008. For several terrifying days, credit markets seized up. Exporters and importers all over the world who needed US dollars to conduct business couldn’t secure financing, and trade threatened to grind to a halt. The Federal Reserve stepped in to provide dollars via “swaps” with other central banks, but not every country found itself first in line to obtain relief. It was this crisis that provided the impetus for China to negotiate bilateral currency swap agreements with several of its largest trading partners, including Indonesia, Argentina, Australia, and Brazil.
The RMB’s increasing role in trade between China and other countries
Because few people understand what central bank currency swaps actually are, or how they function, the signing of these agreements has given rise to the misapprehension that the Renminbi has already taken on a more prominent international role that includes being held as a reserve currency. In fact, no currency reserves have been exchanged. The “swaps” are simply an emergency back-up in the event of another crisis. It is unclear how such swaps, if implemented, could be unwound except through careful stage management, since there is no global market for banks to replenish their Renminbi balances, once deployed. For now, that is a bridge nobody is too worried about having to cross.
In any event, the much-touted currency swaps that China has entered into are a tailored response to a specific set of concerns, and in no way herald the Renminbi’s arrival as a fully functional global currency.
Of course, China is not Honduras, Laos, or even Argentina. China now has the second largest economy in the world, and is the world’s largest exporter. There are plenty of people around the world who want to buy Chinese goods, or make investments in China, and would be willing to acquire Renminbi to do so. Thus, the Renminbi fulfills at least the first criteria that made the US dollar a globally accepted currency: it represents a claim that many people wish to possess.
In response, China has begun to allow companies to invoice and pay for import and export transactions in Renminbi, rather than a foreign currency. Starting with a pilot program in 2009, settlement in Renminbi grew four-fold in 2011 to 2 trillion yuan ($330 billion), or 9% of China’s foreign trade, and in March 2012 was made available to all firms nationwide.
The growth in yuan-denominated settlement, and in offshore holdings of Renminbi in Hong Kong, have been hailed as a sign of the currency’s inexorable rise to global dominance. But critics, including Chinese economist Yu Yongding, have pointed out that Renminbi settlement has been heavily lopsided towards imports, resulting in a net outflow of the yuan. They argue that this currency outflow has been driven more by speculative anticipation of Renminbi appreciation, and by opportunities for exchange rate arbitrage, than by any desire to hold Renminbi as a genuinely useful currency. Beyond these immediate concerns, however, the imbalance in yuan settlement raises a more fundamental challenge to China’s long-term vision for the Renminbi.
Two undesirable scenarios in RMB’s internationalization and the solutions
In the 1960s, the economist Robert Triffin observed an interesting dilemma involving the dollar’s role as the dominant global currency. In order for the dollar to be a desirable currency to possess, it has to buy things that everyone all over the world wants. But in order to meet that need, the dollar has to be readily obtainable, which means the U.S. must run a balance of payments deficit – in other words, it has to export currency either by running a trade deficit or by channeling a very large amount of investment abroad. For the dollar to be a global currency, there has to be some way for people around the world to get their hands on dollars.
Up until very recently, China has been running surpluses on both the current and capital accounts. The result is that, far from Renminbi accumulating abroad, China has accumulated a massive stockpile of $3 trillion in foreign currency reserves. Foreign buyers can’t pay for Chinese exports in Renminbi because, in net terms at least, they’ve had little chance to earn Renminbi. And unless China starts running a trade deficit, or opens its capital account and allows a lot more investment to flow overseas, any yuan the Chinese use to pay for imports only adds to the sum of foreign currency left in China’s official reserves – heightening, rather than reducing, China’s dependence on dollars. For the Renminbi to take on a more prominent international role, much less emerge as the world’s chief reserve currency, would require a dramatic change in China’s relationship to the global economy – a change it is far from clear China either anticipates or desires.
Opening China’s capital account is the key to another obstacle facing the Renminbi: where, if investors do hold yuan, they are supposed to put them? According to McKinsey, 40% of global capital markets are denominated in US dollars, giving investors, including central banks, deep and liquid markets in which to maintain large dollar balances. China, including Hong Kong, accounts for just 4% — mostly in equities, and a large part of it barred to foreign investors. China has tried to fill the void by issuing so-called “dim sum” bonds, yuan-denominated securities sold in Hong Kong: 35.7 billion yuan’s worth in 2010, and 131 billion in 2011. But as long as the offshore market in “dim sum” bonds remains set apart in quarantined isolation from Mainland capital markets, it risks sharing the same fate as the stunted and illiquid B share market. The only viable solution is for China to finish the process it began in the 1980s and make the Renminbi fully convertible on the capital account.
Allowing free flows of capital is really the only way China can – in time – develop into the kind of global financing hub that could support a truly international currency. The problem, for China’s leaders, is that achieving that goal requires giving up a substantial amount of control over the economy. Economists call it the “trilemma,” or the “impossible trinity”: no country can allow free flows of capital, support a fixed exchange rate, and manage an independent monetary policy at the same time. One of them has to go. And as the Japanese discovered with their “big bang” in the mid-1990s, opening China’s financial system to outside market forces would make it a lot harder to hide and quietly manage any bad debt problems lurking in Chinese banks.
So the question is not just whether the Renminbi has the potential to become a truly international currency, but whether China wants to go down the path that could make it one. That path involves risks and rewards, obstacles and opportunities, but wherever it leads, it will not leave the Chinese economy unchanged.
Patrick: You could have saved yourself a long articles and lots of quotes!
China is a net creditor, thus a Chinese currency cannot be a reserve currency. Simple as that. It can’t be done.
When China becomes a net importer they might issue sovereign bonds, but they will be sold immediately for USD – nobody wants to be stuck with monopoly-money once the game is over.
In truth the Chinese use corn as currency.
China has tried to keep the RMB undervalued with respect to USD – collecting a lot of US debt – which eventually will be converted into US sovereign bonds.
Now all that lolly in the currency reserves around the world is just dandy for the US. They can issue tons of sovereign bonds that carry no interest. As long as China is a net creditor the US will not have to pay for the goods they have imported.
When China turns a net importer, which it will as it cannot feed its own population – the market price on food – typically corn will rise. So China has short changed itself when they exported.
Presently they are short changing themselves by overpricing of energy and raw materials – which they shortly wont need, as China is winding down.
They will end up with short changing themselves when food prices go through the roof – that food will have to be paid for in USD.
Don’t want to part with your USD – splendid – it is you that is starving, not the USA.
The only way around this conundrum is realising that money is debt, and debt has quality.
A Spanish sovereign bond is denominated in EUR, but would you prefer it to a German Bundesanleihe? If you are feeble minded – possibly – China has power shopped Spanish sovereign bonds – the interest rate was nice. Fair enough – there is a considerable risk you wouldn’t see your money again – ever.
Now Germany runs a surplus (or close enough) consistently, so they are a bit short of debt. The outstanding German debt dates back to the time when they bought East Germany (the DDR) – cash. They overpaid the Russian, but small matter – a fool and his money are soon parted.
Now Putin is a lot of things; but not a fool. Even he has teeth grinding accepted that German sovereign bonds do in fact buy stuff, so a major part of the Russian currency reserve is in Bundesanleihen – even though they yield a negative interest -. stuff Russian wants gets dearer.
What do you do if You are the toughest, meanest Finance Minister on earth: Wolfgang Schäuble – and are caught short of debt – at least in the scale demanded?
Well – you borrow it!
Germany lends Spain EUR for their failed banks (actually deposits fled to German sovereign bonds). They lend the Spaniards their own money at 3% and issue Bundesanleihen at 1%.
What if Spain doesn’t pay? Oh, they will!
Spain has so much debt, that they constantly need refinancing of their short maturity sovereign debt. And if they don’t lead a responsible life – hunting tax-evaders and tax pensioners – you know – the little merry occupations of a responsible government – they will be denied credit (7% on a sovereign bond is in practice a vehement NO from the bank).
When Spain runs out of debt potential there are lots of other defaulters in Europe – Italy and France spring to mind – where the process may be repeated. Germany can print sovereign bonds for a very long time – borrowing somebody else’s debt. Germany has recourse – others have not.
Now China tried to overvalue their currency against the EUR and kept it undervalued against the USD. They offered solar cells – among other things at a hyper discount price – payable in EUR. But what happened when the Chinese tried to cash the EUR into USD?
Strangely enough the EUR dropped 12-15% against the USD – so China not only sold at a discount; but also lost when they cashed the cheques that were not honoured in former rate to the USD.
Chinese president even paid insignificant Denmark a visit trying to purchase pork – we make an awful lot of them. Splendid! But when it came to pricing the oinkers – we had to inform the Chinese dignitary, that as long as American Joe Sixpack has a partiality for spare ribs (Yes, Carlsberg is Danish as well!) – we had another figure in USD in mind. So he probably got a few containers of sows ears – big article in China – pigs ears that is; not containers.
So Danish consumers will have to eat through the best cuts at fire sale prices to produce all those pigs ears – 50 million of them annually. Normally given to pets to munch on; but they might be persuaded to use hams instead. Kindness to animals is a national trait – pigs though beg to differ.
As to Chinese pointing out our dwarf size and ridiculous attitude – well – we had to point out that is was our century long experience, that embargoing marine barracks with respect to spare ribs and beer tends to bring unpleasantness – have you ever heard of US troops destroying a brewery?
The point being: You can’t undervalue your currency with respect to two different reserve currencies simultaneously – a small thing called arbitrage prevents that from succeeding. You might try – it’s your funeral.
Thomas – RMB is on its way to being a global reserve currency, whether there is a trade deficit or not. As Patrick pointed out, it is the desire of outsiders to hold and trade in RMB determine the speed at which the transition happens. My bet is that it happens within 10 years.
Patrick – the swap is also being used for current trade settlements and not just as a backup for a us$ markets freeze. Se Asia is using more of it now. As long as there is enough two way trade plus exporters and importers can avoid fx charges, then why not?
No!
As long as China is trying to keep their currency undervalued with respect to the USD and overvalued vis-a-vis the EUR arbitrage will conspire to hit China both ways.
The thing is that there is not going to be a two way trade for much longer. China Will have to start being a net importer, where exporters won’t care what China thinks – prices on grain (in USD) will just go up to equalise the unrealistic expectations.
Thomas : you wrote that the renminbi can’t be a reserve currency, because china is a net creditor. As I rember Jim Rogers always saying, that the US has changed from a creditor nation (until the 80’s) to a debtor nation. Al that time, the US dollar has been a reserve currency. In a creditor situation and in a debtor situation. Why can’t china start the same way ?
Actually, being a net creditor was the main way the United States supplied dollars to the world economy in the 1950s and early ’60s, despite running current account surpluses. Running a capital account deficit that is larger than your current account surplus is one way to become a net exporter of currency. That is why, in my article, I wrote that China would either have to start running trade deficits OR open its capital account and allow a great deal more investment to flow abroad.
Patrick: You are right!
That is exactly what Germany is doing at the moment.
Standing corrected I have for long been an advocate of China investing heavily in Russian infrastructure – not Chinese.
The purpose of which should have been opening the vast Russian agriculture for grain production, thus depressing world market prices on food.
Russia’s problem is that their tax base is limited by their oil export. 2/3 of all Russian tax revenue is export tax on oil. And the signs that Russia’s oligarchs investing in railroads are few – to say the least.
ok… thnx… start to understand it
thank you ..they don’t have change jet ..(not to much)
nice article just i have to say monetary system in chine was not right way in basic of international trade ok now fom 4-5.99 i just read ..and this is one reason export import chines is slowdown of course and crisis in euz is important reason too
Princess 1960 – perhaps due to my flawed English – I don’t quite understand what You are writing. But would You care to clarify, as I THINK You have a valid point somewhere.